The Torch Magazine,
The Journal and Magazine of the
International Association of Torch Clubs
For 91 Years
A Peer-Reviewed
Quality Controlled
Publication
ISSN Print 0040-9440
ISSN Online 2330-9261
Spring
2017
Volume 90, Issue 3
The
Nashville Experiment, 1863:
Regulating With,
Not Against, the Market
by John Fockler
Major General
William S. Rosecrans had a
problem. Rosecrans was commander
of the Union's Army of the Cumberland,
based largely in and around the city
of Nashville, Tennessee.
Rosecrans had been in command of the
army's XIV Corps (which became the
Army of the Cumberland) since October
of 1862. In addition to being a
base of supply for the army, Union
troops were also using the city as a
kind of rest and recreation
center. And therein lay the
problem.
The presence of so
many young and unattached soldiers
wandering around the city had
attracted another army of sorts,
nearly 1500 "public women," as one of
the contemporary euphemisms put
it. In other words, they were
prostitutes (Serratore). By the spring
of 1863, Rosecrans and his staff were
becoming extremely concerned with the
inevitable concurrence of nineteenth
century prostitution: syphilis and
gonorrhea. Estimates of the
level of infection in Rosecrans' army
ranged as high as ten percent.
In the Union Army as a whole, "At
least 8.2 percent of Union troops
would be infected with one or the
other before war's end—nearly half the
battle-injury rate of 17.5 percent,
even without accounting for those who
contracted a disease and didn't know
it or didn't mention it—and the
treatments (most involved mercury),
when they worked, could sideline a man
for weeks" (Serratore).
The first solution
that occurred to Union Army officers
was the obvious one: remove the
problem by removing the prostitutes,
assumed to be the source of the
problem. In July, Lieutenant
Colonel George Spaulding, Provost
Marshal of Nashville, led police and
troops on a raid of the city's
brothels. One source says
hundreds of women were rounded up, and
"111 of Nashville's most infamous sex
workers" (Moss) were loaded aboard a
steamship called—I kid you not!—the
Idahoe. The ship was then
dispatched downriver to Louisville,
Kentucky, where, it was hoped, it
could offload its dangerous
cargo. But armed guards at
Louisville, and later on at Cincinnati
and other, lesser, ports, prevented
the "soiled doves" from leaving the
ship. The Cincinnati Gazette
reported:
There
does not seem to be much desire on
the part of our authorities to
welcome such a large addition to the
already overflowing numbers engaged
in their peculiar profession, and
the remonstrances were so urgent
against their being permitted to
land that that boat has taken
over to the Kentucky shore; but the
authorities of Newport and
Covington have no greater
desire for their company, and the
consequence is that the poor girls
are still kept on board the
boat. It is said (on what authority
we are unable to discover)
that the military order issued
in Nashville has been revoked in
Washington, and that they will all
be returned to Nashville again.
(qtd. in Serratore)
At so it was. After a cruise of
28 days, the Idahoe found
itself back at Nashville, still
carrying the women. Plan A, removing
the "business girls" from Nashville,
had failed. It was time for Plan
B. On August 20, 1863, Spaulding
ordered all prostitutes in the city of
Nashville to register with the
military government. A similar
answer to the issue of prostitution
had been in place in France since
being initiated during the Napoleonic
Era. But this plan was not a
simple process of tracking the women.
Each woman who registered would be
provided with a license to practice
her trade. To be kept current,
each prostitute would submit to a
weekly medical checkup, for which she
would be charged fifty cents. If
found to be infected with a venereal
disease, the woman would be
hospitalized and treated. Women
found to be engaging in prostitution
without a license would be subject to
a sentence of 30 days in the workhouse
(Wilson). The program was to be
self-sufficient, with the proceeds
from the licensing and inspection to
be applied to the cost of treating
those in whom disease was found.
Two hospitals were designated for the
treatment of venereal disease victims,
Hospital 11 for soldiers and Hospital
15 for the prostitutes (Wilson). In
those days, three-quarters of a
century before the discovery of
penicillin, treatment for syphilis and
gonorrhea was possible and frequently
effective, but involved the injection
of mercury, itself a toxic substance,
and required weeks or months to
complete. Nevertheless, the
program was considered a success.
The program was
extremely popular with Nashville's
prostitutes, who eagerly showed
potential customers the certificates
showing them to be disease-free.
They were also grateful both to be
free of the risk of arrest and to have
access to the best available treatment
if they were found to be
infected. At the program's peak,
August 1864, more than 500 prostitutes
had been licensed, including 50 black
women, who had initially been excluded
from the program.
Unsurprisingly, infection rates among
Union soldiers declined. The
program was later replicated in
Memphis, also a Union Army supply
center, with similar results.
The program was even reasonably
popular with the general civilian
population. On August 24, 1863,
the Nashville City Council postponed
indefinitely legislation banning
prostitutes "from riding in hacks with
soldiers" (Wilson).
We have now seen that trying to remove
prostitutes, and by implication,
prostitution, from wartime Nashville
failed, while legalizing, regulating,
and taxing it succeeded. But
why? My argument is that its
success represents a simple case study
in basic economics. It succeeded
because it worked with market
forces, rather than trying to work
against them.
When we consider
market forces, we tend to think of how
they affect the availability and price
of the goods and services we buy or
sell. Perhaps the most basic of
these is the law of supply and
demand. This economic principle
says that the balance between the
supply of a commodity and the demand
for that commodity will affect its
price. If demand rises and
supply remains constant, the price
goes up. The same is true if
demand remains constant and supply
falls, a condition we frequently but
temporarily see with products that are
illegal to buy, sell, or
produce. If demand remains
constant and supply increases, the
price goes down, as it does if demand
falls and supply remains
constant. The law can work
backwards, in a sense, if artificial
forces affect price. If the
price at which a product may be sold
is capped, the supply of that product
will decline. If the price of a
product or service is subsidized,
supply will rise. If a minimum
price greater than the market value of
a good or service is mandated, demand
will decline.
Another market force may be expressed
as an analogy to the famous scientific
truism that nature abhors a
vacuum. Markets abhor a vacuum
as well. If outside forces cut
off the supply of a given product or
service for which a demand still
exists, a new source of supply will
develop. In wartime Nashville,
before the Idahoe returned and
Spaulding's Plan B went into effect,
this was already beginning to be
seen. According to one of my
sources, the only immediate effect of
the removal of the Idahoe prostitutes—all
of whom were white, by the way—was
that black prostitutes filled the
void. Without doubt, other
prostitutes would have been drawn to
Nashville even had the eviction stood,
because the demand would have been
unaffected (Wilson).
Are market forces
natural laws? Some have tried to
argue that they are not. One
video popular on social media a couple
of years ago featured a purported
physical scientist claiming that they
could be ignored or "engineered,"
because they are not "physical
laws." Another source I came
across, in passing, implied that
market forces did not exist until they
were invented in the Eighteenth
Century. But market forces
explain why Byzantine and Islamic
coins are found in Viking graves, how
the Silk Road functioned for centuries
before Adam Smith, and why the
production of purple dye helped build
the city of Tyre. Nothing else
does.
The basic rules of
economics—the basic market forces—are,
I would argue, natural laws and are,
in fact, a subcategory of social
psychology. They describe how
numbers of people respond to
particular stimuli. But, some
would argue, people do not always
respond in terms of material
gain. That is quite true.
But even this seeming transcendence of
the marketplace falls within the realm
of economic law if you concede, as
economists always do, that people
"profit" from non-material
rewards.
I'm a blood donor. I recently
recorded my 162nd donation with the
Red Cross. I've never gotten a
nickel out of it, but I've been
rewarded with smiles and thank-yous,
with a little jolt to my self-esteem,
and with a feeling that donating is a
way of pulling my weight in this
society. Others may find
non-material rewards in other ways,
but the truism that people may be
motivated by rewards other than
material gain does not contradict
market forces. It's a part of
them.
One always ignores market
forces at one's own peril. We
may liken fighting market forces to
squeezing a toothpaste tube with the
cap screwed on tight. Squeeze
long enough or hard enough, and that
toothpaste is going to come out, but
probably not where you expect it or
want it.
In
the case of the Nashville experiment,
the operative market force involved
was the concept that "nature abhors a
vacuum." There was a demand
among the Union troops in Nashville
for sexual services. There were
women ready and able to supply these
services, for a price. The
attempt to remove the supply failed,
and even had there been momentary
success, other sources of supply (as
we have seen) would have
developed. There is no evidence
in any of my sources that attempting
to reduce demand was even
considered. In wartime, there
are generally better uses for soldiers
than locking them up for patronizing
prostitutes, and Rosecrans (who was a
West Point-trained professional
soldier) and his staff knew far too
well that there was no effective way
to keep soldiers from seeking out
prostitutes, anyway. They could
not stop the demand and they could not
get rid of the supply. What they
could do—and did!—was make the supply
safer. Even more than that, the
method they found, licensing,
examination and treatment, made it
advantageous for the suppliers of the
services to comply and safer
for the customers to buy. Thus,
the regulated source was more
attractive to the prospective customer
than any hypothetical unregulated
competition would be. This is
what's called a win-win situation.
Sadly, today, we are still in the
process of learning these
lessons. In statements as part
of his campaign for the Republican
nomination for President in 2016,
Governor Chris Christie of New Jersey
vowed that as far as laws permitting
marijuana use in Oregon and Colorado
go, he "will crack down and not permit
it" (Ferner). President Trump's new
Attorney General, Jeff Sessions, has
pledged to continue the prohibitory
policies of the previous
administration, under which large
cannabis operations are still subject
to Federal raid, even where legal
under state law (Siegel). Politicians
of all stripes in this country
continue to support the so-called "War
on Drugs," despite its self-evident
failure and the fact that other
nations, such as Portugal and the
Netherlands, have produced much better
results with programs that treat
dangerous narcotics more like the way
General Rosecrans treated
prostitution. Yet gambling,
which not so long ago was widely
illegal, is now widely legal and
regulated most places in the United
States in one form or another, and
while gambling is still in many ways a
dangerous practice with many
unfortunate, and sometimes innocent,
victims, the very least we can say is
that Harrah's and Caesar's Palace
don't shoot each other over market
share. Neither do Phillip Morris
and Lorillard.
Basic economic laws
had already been formulated by the
third quarter of the Eighteenth
Century, and there is evidence that
some scholars understood them much
earlier than that. I do not know
how familiar General Rosecrans (who
was, as noted, educated to be a
military officer and engineer) or
Colonel Spaulding were with
them. Curiously enough, though,
both would eventually wind up in
Congress, where dealing with economic
issues was and is a daily task.
But at the end of the day, it doesn't
matter whether they understood why
their licensing plan worked where
nothing else did. All that
matters is that regulating with
markets does work, and regulating or
prohibiting against them does not.
Works Cited
Ferner, Matt. "Chris Christie: 'I Will
Crack Down and Not Permit' Legal
Marijuana as President." Huffington
Post, April 14, 2015.
Serratore, Angela. "The Curious Case of
Nashville's Frail Sisterhood."
Smithsonian.com. July 8, 2013.
Siegel, Alec. "Jeff Sessions Signals
Marijuana Enforcement Will Remain the
Same." Lawstreetmedia.com. February 14,
2017.
Wilson, William Moss. "The Nashville
Experiment." Opinionator blog.
nytimes.com. December 5, 2013.
Author's Biography
John Fockler has a bachelor's degree
in history from Colgate
University. A "lifer" in the
hotel industry, he has managed
properties in Ohio and
Pennsylvania.
He has been an
official of the Libertarian Party in
Ohio, and is currently serving as a
member of the state central
committee. That activism has
been influenced by his lifelong
interest in matters historical and
economic, and, in turn, has informed
his view of such issues.
Fockler and his wife, Cathy,
are the parents of two daughters and
grandparents of three
grandsons. He has been a
member of Torch since the late
1990s, and is a part president of
both the Youngstown and Akron Torch
Clubs.
"The Nashville Experiment, 1863" is
his eleventh appearance in The
Torch. It was presented to the
Youngstown Torch Club on September
21, 2015.
©2017 by the International
Association of Torch Clubs
Return to Home Page
|
|